various paradoxes in which they get involved. Of these the following is a further example close at hand. We are told that the fight over collectivization was at its height in the year 1931. " Beginning with the calamitous slaughter of livestock in many areas in 1929-1930, the recalcitrant peasants defeated, during the years 1931 and 1932, all the efforts of the Soviet Government to get the land adequately cultivated " (p. 265); yet have we not learned on an earlier page that during the same period the Communist Party was enormously popular among the peasants ? We have "been told that " it is significant of the character and popularity of the Party that out of 59,797 -village Soviets at the 1931 election, 35,155 chose a Party member as elected president, who is always a member of the local presidium, whilst 3,242 others elected a Comsomol " (pp. 31-32). We are thus asked to believe that, at a time when the peasants were killing their cows in a desperate struggle against the Com- munist policy, the popularity of the Party among them was so great that it caused them to elect a member of the Party as soviet chairman practically whenever or wherever they could find one. One is left to wonder whether perhaps the word " char- acter," associated with the word " popularity " in the above passage, might not indicate a reservation which resolves the paradox : " character " might perhaps stand for " terroristic character." The short chapter entitled " In Whose Interest Does the Government Act ? " (p. 449) suggests, however, that the village soviet chairmen of 1931 are only a special case of a more comprehensive parados:. It seems that in Russia it is quite customary for the agricultural population to elect representatives who 107